Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  136 / 298 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 136 / 298 Next Page
Page Background

Horst Steinke

136

tory, first as home economics in the state of the families, and then as political

economy in aristocratic and monarchic commonwealths» (p. 153). The core of

human society and culture therefore consists of the compound «economic-

political power», rather than the intersection of the «social-political» dimen-

sions. At the same time, Pipa adds an important qualification that substantially

revises the earlier assessment: «This is not to say that the economic element is

determinant in Vico’s system. Economy is subordinated not only to politics,

but also to natural law […]. Finally, religion is above (but not outside) econo-

my […]. Vico’s concept of providence as heteronomy of ends is a peremptory

caveat to any reduction of his system to economic determinism» (pp. 154-

155). This is not very different from the view espoused here.

Still another view is advanced by J. O’Neill,

On the History of the Human

Senses in Vico and Marx,

in

Vico and Contemporary Thought

,

cit., Part 2, pp. 179-

186): «The fundamental thesis of

poetic economics

is that man is a work of his

own senses and intellect and that these are never so alien to him, even in their

remote beginnings, as not to build upon them our own humanity» (p. 181). At

this conceptual level, O’Neill finds certain consonances with «Marxist eco-

nomics», which may be debatable.

273

To be counted among these “economists” is a student of Vico’s, A.

Genovesi, and his work

Lezioni di Commercio ossia di Economia Civile

(1765). See

L. Haddad,

The Evolutionary Economics of Giambattista Vico

, cit., p. 18. Genovesi,

in fact, assumed in 1754 in Naples, the first faculty position for economics in

Europe. See V. Hösle,

Einleitung

, cit., p. XCIV. Special mention needs to be

made of F. Galiani (1728-1787) and his

Trattato della moneta

(1750) and

Dia-

logues sur le commerce des blés

(1770). In G. Tagliacozzo’s view, «Galiani’s singling

out of some of the most significant principles of the

New Science

for use as

foundation for his own economic thought was so skillful and faithful to its

source that it made Galiani’s economics a true corollary of Vico’s ideas and

established Galiani as the legitimate founder of economic Vichianism» (Id.,

Economic Vichianism: Vico, Galiani, Croce. Economics, Economic Liberalism

, in

Giam-

battista Vico: An International Symposium

, cit., pp. 349-368, pp. 366-367). How-

ever, most relevant for our argument is the admission: «In none of his [Vico’s]

works, however, did he pay specific attention to problems of economics

strictu

sensu

» (p. 349).

274

For a historical overview of economic analysis and writing essentially

contemporaneous with Vico, see T. Hutchison,

Before Adam Smith: The Emer-

gence of Political Economy, 1662-1776

, London, Basil Blackwell, 1988, pp. 107-

181. Counted among these early “economists” are Pierre Boisguilbert (1646-

1714), Bernard Mandeville (1671-1733), John Law (1671-1729), George

Berkeley (1685-1753), Ernst Ludwig Carl (1682-1743), Richard Cantillon